My good friend Pedro Linares has
been pointing lately a surprising number of good articles in the web to me,
from this little piece in the New Yorker: Better kind of Happiness (it alleviates my guilt from reading
that quintessentially elitist outfit that my friends also indulge in such
habit), which prefigured many of the ideas
I later reflected in my latest post on how to live (Live Kantianly!, or engage in long-term projects
that are hard and keep you engaged, ‘cuz Kant already told you so, you moron!)
to this other piece from Acemoglu and Restrepo Job race: machines vs. humans
which he posted in his always commendable blog. The latter, even though full of
logical flaws in reasoning that reveal the sad state of what passes today for
advanced social science, got me thinking about the stated race between
automating technologies (job killing) and the supposed creation of cognitively
more complex tasks that it enables (job creating), and allowed me to reach a
number of conclusions that I’ll share in this post, as they clarify the likely
form that our civilization’s final demise may take in the next decade.
First, as I
mentioned in my recent review of Robert Gordon’s magisterial The Rise and Fall of American Growth (3rd Industrial Revolution? fuggedaboudid!), in this area surprisingly the
techno-optimists are driven to the gloomier predictions, as they (wrongly)
believe the (inexistent) acceleration of innovations will speed up the pace of
automation and drive countless (and ever growing) hordes of workers (starting
with the less skilled ones, but soon affecting the ones engaged in more
cognitively demanding jobs) out of work. On the contrary, according to Gordon
there is not much innovation going on (as measured by the ability of new technology
to produce increases in Total Factor Productivity, or TFP, which has been
notoriously flat since a comparatively anemic spurt in the 90’s of last
century), which means that the much-touted and much-ballyhooed automation that
would condemn most of us and our descendants to technological unemployment is
simply not happening (here you can find none other than Robert Gordon himself
explaining it in Vox: The Master Speaks!).
Everything
else being equal, the lack of technological progress (in Acemoglu and
Restrepo’s model, the diminishing pressure of automation, even in an
environment of “cheap capital” which would make substituting for human labor
attractive) should ease the pressure on labor and thus contribute to a decrease
in the rate of unemployment, an upward trend in salaries and a growing
percentage of labor’s reward as a percentage of GDP (as opposed to capital,
which would see a diminishing reward). As that doesn’t reflect at all what we
see, we have to conclude that either the model is crap (my first option) or
that everything else is not equal (also true). I should note that the model
mentions the existence of automatic stabilizers that should prevent it from
letting one of the competing tendencies get too much ahead the other one.
According to the authors, in a situation of crazy technical progress, with
automation getting seriously out of whack the downward pressure on salaries
would make it more attractive for employers to hire humans to do cognitively
more demanding tasks, thus creating new openings for positions that did not
exist previously that in turn would increase the number of jobs (countervailing
the downward pressure on salaries, as the new jobs would be better remunerated
than the lost ones).
There is, of
course, a more parsimonious explanation of why the progress of technology since
the Industrial Revolution has not left all of us idle (Leontieff’s paradox,
more about it later): as more people have lost their jobs salaries have indeed
go down and capital’s bargaining position has improved, thus moving the supply
curve for labor to the left (people “at the margin” were willing to work for
less), thus intersecting the demand curve at a higher level of employment, even
if such employment was worse paid for a total higher number of hours (on
aggregate, although it may go either way for the average number of hours worked
by each individual worker). As I showed in my post about fiscal policy, even
one that dwarfed the content of a Keynesian wettest dreams would not do much to
change that and get more people back to work (lots of supply and demand curves) but remember how I laid out in
that post the way things have played out historically: the reason technology
has not consistently depressed the total employment figure is because
population has consistently added additional consumers to the market, thus
increasing the aggregate demand more than what the aggregate supply could meet
just by the technological improvements. Thus industry (and services) had to resort
to adding more of just about any factor (more machinery, but also more workers)
to meet it. But population has more or less stopped growing, except for a few
remnants of African villages that have no resources whatsoever to become a
source of additional consumers, and are busily trying to migrate to more
promising (economic) climates, while the potential receiving locations are
similarly busy trying to avoid them doing so.
So I think we
are on the last ropes of Leontieff’s paradox. We have seen people finding work
in the face of labor-reducing inventions because such inventions were not
enough by themselves to supply the appetites (continuously whetted by a very
successful dominant reason, y’all know that) of an ever growing demand. Now you
may say that even if the number of people demanding additional thingies has
stabilized, nothing prevents each one of them from wanting even more, so the
aggregate demand could in theory keep on growing forever, even in the absence
of population growth. That would be indeed the final goal of a sane economic
policy: see how we can stimulate a perpetual improvement of people’s standard
of living without a perpetual increase in their numbers, so they produce ever
more for each individual without an ever increasing environmental footprint
(for example, by providing each other ever more fulfilling services, which have
typically a lower consumption of non-renewable resources than thingies, as things have a tendency of
requiring a whole dirty industry behind them to be manufactured and
distributed). The “not increase the environmental footprint” is not an
additional and extravagant condition that I’ve conjured out of thin air, but a
“contour condition” that has to be taken into account if we don’t want to run
very rapidly into nature’s limits and trigger all sort of perverse negative
feedback effects that send the whole system crashing down (something we may be
already doing, btw). Unfortunately, such goal is intrinsically unattainable.
To find out
why we need to delve deeper in an aspect I touched only in passing in my post
about the limits of fiscal policy: the subtle but consequential difference
between the industrial (and agricultural and extractive) sectors and the
service sector, a difference that will show why Acemoglu and Restrepo’s model
(along with most techno-optimists set of assumptions) is an elegant amount of
sheer bunk. Such difference is much obscured by the fact that both products
(for which it may be more clear to use the old Marxist term “commodities”) and
services are exchanged in the market, so both categories are offered by the
best price they can fetch, and end up being paid for in the same currency
(money), and thus it is easy to think that both
have an equivalent “value” that is in the end determined by the amount
of labor that goes in its production, may be somewhat adjusted by the time that
the person doing the labor had to devote to acquire the required skills to
perform it. For this to be true Jamie Dimon (estimated salary 27 million $ in
2016, or 10,800 $/hour assuming he worked a quite taxing 2,500 hours that year)
should have devoted about 1,000 hours of learning per hour, as to offset the
difference with the 12 to 15 $/hour his lower salaried employees will perceive
in Chase (and after a “generous” raise, as in 2015 they were making a paltry 10
$/hour), or, to explain a single year difference, he would need to have devoted
1,000 years more than his janitors of arduous study to prepare himself for the
extraordinary skill of leading a major financial institution that, let’s not
forget, was essentially bankrupt five years ago and had to be bailed out with
taxpayers money (that unfortunately didn’t came with any clause regarding the
acceptable compensation levels of its top executives). Well, that’s my circuitous
way of saying that the labor theory of value is baloney (something I already
did here: Value and Wages), but that doesn’t take us an inch
closer to solving the problem at hand.
So back to
the difference between offering services in the market and offering material
products (commodities), the fact that both are given to whoever can pay the
highest price for them obscures, as I said, a fundamental difference:
commodities can be stored and loose value (understood as the price they can
command, I don’t want to go all metaphysical here) very slowly if at all, while
every hour a service provider is not providing the service is an hour lost
forever, that he will never be able to recover. That makes the services market
inherently more buyer dominated, and puts an additional pressure on the
providers to find someone willing to pay for their time, as they can’t afford
the luxury to keep the product of their labor sitting idle in a warehouse
waiting for a better deal. I am aware that a famed neurosurgeon or a
sought-after life coach have throngs of people willing to pay a premium for
their services, but let’s be honest here: such figures constitute so tiny a
percentage of the labor force that we can entirely ignore them in our analysis
(although they are very useful to justify the status quo and convey the message
that for everyone willing to put the time and devote the necessary effort there
are great rewards to be reaped from the current system in any walk of life). We
can confidently state that for the vast (90% or more) of people offering
services in the market, such market is tough, they can not claim to have any
substantial advantage over the other providers, there is fierce competition and
they have little influence over the price they can command.
You may say
such is life, the market, although a stern master, is still the best social
mechanism for optimally assigning finite resources to the most socially desired
ends and for distributing them, and that applies as much to services as to
goods. Doesn’t really matter if those resources are small mud huts,
Versailles-like 10,000 square feet mansions, little mopeds, scrumptious
Ferraris, a 6$ haircut or a 1,000 $ massage in a luxurious spa. The best way to
ensure everybody receives as close as possible what she wants, given means
distributed by as close as possible to just dessert, is by the magical action
of the free market. Market schmarket, I say, and anybody that believes that
load of bunk has been either brainwashed or born without a wholly functioning
brain. Back to my argument, I would say the services sector is morally tainted,
and it not only doesn’t conduct to proper human flourishing, but seriously
stunts the moral development of people trapped in it. And I say trapped with
full understanding that the investment banker and the interior designer that
earn gazillions fool themselves thinking they are making a killing and are most
fortunate to have chosen such profitable line of activity to devote their life
to. They are equally wrong, and should see themselves as not that different of
the poor schmuck flipping burgers in a nondescript joint in the middle of
nowhere.
Again, when
most economists discuss the service economy, they tend to focus on its
glitziest aspect: business consultants, web designers, designers of successful
apps that rake in millions… although the reality is somewhat grimmer: poorly
paid housemaids, janitors, waiters, repairmen from foreign countries without
legal status, nail polishers, retail clerks, call center attendants on a
Taylorist schedule, programmers on perpetual crunch time whose salary barely
allows them to make ends meet, bank tellers, designers in advertising agencies
working 20 hours a day for creative directors they will never replace… what
they all have in common is that, regardless of how glamorous the title they are
given sounds, their contribution is pretty easy to replace, so they are paid
little, they can be fired on a whim and they have little prospect of
professional advancement. You may counter that they should build a
“differential set of skills” that made them stand out from the potential
competition, and I would laugh you off the room. Build when? Using what
resources? By definition, the majority of the population (in a services economy
as in an agrarian, or an industrial one) can not have above average skills, or
capabilities.
And that’s why the powerful, the clever, the wealthy and the well educated find the whole arrangement so lovely and convenient. When all those features tend to coincide, and when such coincidence becomes, through assortative mating and high heritability mostly transferred from one generation to the next, you have all the ingredients for a class-based society of low intergenerational mobility where the elite becomes more and more detached from the concerns of the average “guy in the street”, where inequality grows and human’s natural selfishness, unbridled, allow public benefits to whither. Oooops, just the society we live in! And a society where only “services” grow and supposedly provide opportunity for all is a society where the slightest modicum of justice has become nearly impossible to achieve, as such services are the more or less fancy names given to the starkest servitude, to the centuries old exploitation of man (or woman) by man.
Think about
it. I worked the first fifteen years of my career in a professional services
firm, and the thing that never stopped to amaze me was precisely how servile,
how debased even the most powerful partners (most already filthy rich, but you
know what they say: you are never rich enough) were towards the clients that
had in their hands their further professional advancement. In such firms,
unsurprisingly, the best career is offered to those that can sell, because
selling is the whole point of the enterprise, regardless of what the “mission”
and the “vision” state about delivering value to the clients and putting their
interest first and building a better world. Technical competence, being an
inspiring leader towards your
subordinates or being an efficient business operator were all nice
qualities to have, but being able to convince a client (which usually required
obscene amounts of brown-nosing and sycophancy) to hire our services was
absolutely paramount, and dwarfed the importance of any other skill when it
came to promotion. And what is the clue to such convincing? In the service
world, doesn’t matter how much you want to beat around the bush, it is all
about making your potential client believe you will serve him better. Strategic
partnership, win-win situation, maximize the value of the relationship and not
the transaction and unlock hidden value levers my foot, the one who wins the
business in a competitive situation is the one who shows he will be a better server (more docile, more slavish, more
pliant, more obeying, more unprepossessing; and less confrontational, less
arrogant, less unruly, less independent-minded, less free-spirited). Not what
management books teach, huh? I have this shocking piece of news for you, kids:
management books lie (blatantly in most cases).
So service is
mostly about debasing oneself to satisfy the ego of those hiring you (which
many times means kicking the balls of their underlings so they don’t have to do
it themselves) while (in the upper echelons of the profession) lying to
yourself thinking that you are in control, you do it for your own good, you can
choose when to quit, you are the one really taking the decisions and having a
measurable impact in the companies for which you work… if it sounds like the rationalizations
prostitutes use with themselves to justify why they are servicing the next John
it is not a coincidence. But what is of more importance for our current argument
is that in such branch of activity it is difficult both to reach real meaning
and to grow productivity. Stroking your customers’ ego is awfully difficult to
automate, as having a robot tell you how clever you are and how most of your
subordinates are morons doesn’t give the same kick as having a Harvard graduate
tell you the same thing. Seen from the other side of the table, having our best
and brightest young minds spend most of their careers telling old white men in
positions of power how they are so exactly right that their companies should do
little but what they have already decided is not likely to produce breathtaking
technological breakthroughs.
And there you
have it in a nutshell: the growth of the service economy makes it trebly
unlikely we will ever get out of the current stagnation, because:
a) What people is paying for is not to
have a physical need satisfied, but a “spiritual” need (feeling superior to
someone) that requires another human being, and can not be fulfilled by a
machine, it doesn’t matter how intelligent it is
b) The kind of careers such economy
promotes are antithetical to innovation and scientific development, as they
channel the most ambitious, most disciplined and most gifted overall in
activities that can only be described as “self-important brown-nosing”
c) True scientific development is left
mostly to second-rate intelligences (with some notable, highly laudable
exceptions), and further hampered by a deluge of unnecessary regulations (and a
layer of self-inflicted insanity in the form of the academic publication
industry and its peer review creativity-stifling mechanism)
So you can sleep soundly, no robots
are coming to take your jobs (as Gordon notes in the interview linked above, no
robots are being developed for the tasks that occupy the vast majority of the
population that still holds a job, from pushing wheelchairs along hospital
corridors to replacing perishable goods in supermarkets’ shelves), and not much
effort is being devoted to such development, because many of those jobs exist
to allow even the people lowest on the social scale to boss over someone even
lower, independently of cost, effort or economic rationality. We will see the
number of people working drop more and more (although not necessarily find them
in the unemployment roll, as they may just give up even trying to find some
occupation, as the part of this interview with Erik Hurst dealing with time
allocation of youngsters without a college degree highlights: "What are young men doing"),
some robots in traditional manufacturing eating a bit of additional jobs at the
margins, may be applications of AI changing the cognitive content of a bunch of
others (but with no real substitution effect, for reasons I would explain in
another post, other than the fact that the bosses of the substitutable employees
want them to feel important, not because their automatable contribution is that
important).
What will continue happening is that
a higher percentage of the population will work providing “services”, and deriving
less and less satisfaction from it, as the stark “needlessness” of their
activities becomes more and more apparent. Until, of course, they revolt, bring
down civilization as we know it, either because they overthrow the ruling elite
that has been benefitting from their servility -sorry, from their services, or
because they are crushed by the robot army that such elite has developed in the
meantime…
No comments:
Post a Comment