After developing an example of a practical
application of the ADVISE model, a number of questions arise: If a very big
company, that has grown considerably “worse” (less ADVISE and more RACKET), is
still in spite of that worsening considered wildly successful, doesn’t it
somehow point to a flaw in the theory? What good is belonging to an
organization that, from the point of view of its members, is “preferable” for
being adorned with the “right” features, if the verdict of the market contradicts
that preference, and rewards having just the opposite ones?
I’ll note first that this is a
classical conundrum for any management theory: whenever It posits a number of
normative features of its subject (be it qualities of a leader, characteristics
of a company’s culture or functional requirements of an information system),
stubborn reality presents us with as many counterexamples as the wildest
imagination can conceive of instances where leaders (or cultures, or systems)
that show none of those features are (either temporarily or in the long term)
generously rewarded with tons of success. Look no further than the case of Steve Jobs.
Lionized as he is after his death (a visionary! A fearless leader! A
perfectionist that led his company to new heights of excellence (and market
capitalization)!). But according to the biography written by Walter Isaacson
(quite revealing of Jobs character that he only agreed to provide information
to a biographer that had previously devoted his energies to the life of
Newton), and confirmed by countless testimonies every time the subject still
surfaces in social media, he was a jerk, a tyrant, a bad person, a bully, a
sadist and a megalomaniacal egotist. More or less what every book on leadership
tells you not to be, as “better results” are obtained when you are selfless,
nice, understanding, sensitive, compassionate, inclusive, respectful of other
people’s opinions and the like. Just what Jobs what not… (by the way, I’m aware
there is a new biography out there, becoming
Steve Jobs, by Brent Schlender and Rick Tetzeli that presents him in a
quite different light, as a person that learned from the errors of his first
tenure at Apple and came as a much more inclusive, integrating type of leader,
no surprise that both Tim Cook and Jony Ive have praised it extravagantly).
For another funny example, yesterday
I came across this piece by Steve Denning The robots are not coming
maintaining with very weak arguments that “the jobless future is a myth” (well,
he writes in Forbes, so you can not really expect too serious journalism from
such bigoted bunch of “greed is good” paean singers)… the article is crap, but
it directed me to this other priceless piece of entertainment: The havoc a silly organizational model can wreak
which I wanted to comment, as I mentioned the holocracy at Zappos (somewhat
dismissively) in a previous post. Really, have a good read at it, because it
amazes me that any adult with a minimal experience managing anything more
complex than a boy scout group can fall for this egregious example of snake oil
(you can have a look to the “holocracy constitution” here: Just wow!
and note that this is “release 4.1”, in which “natural language” has replaced
“legalistic language”, Jesus Christ, you really couldn’t make this thing up
even if you wanted!). If I were a stakeholder at Zappos I would be demanding Tony
Hsieh’s head for trying to implement such monstrosity, more adequate for a
college fraternity than for an actual company trying to make money. The funny
thing is that Zappos is not some cutting edge technology firm trying to resolve
some of the basic problems of humanity, or some multinational ensemble cryin’
out for an innovative business model to support their ultra complex operations,
but a friggin’ online retailer of shoes based in Las Vegas… shoes that other
people manufacture, and which they just distribute… pretending to change the world and reinvent
the corporation so they can make an additional dime from monetizing what they
can learn from people tastes so as to make them spend a bit more on what they
wrap their feet in.
So, back to the glaring gap between
what theories of management prescribe and what the most cursory observation of
actually successful companies show us. There are two possible reactions by the authors
of such theories. One is to appeal to the inherent complexity of the human
sciences, and declare that “all things being equal” their prescriptions would
have worked, but as all other things are never indeed equal, it doesn’t matter
that much that actually they didn’t. So Apple would have been even more
successful if Jobs had been less of a Jerk, and Zappos would be growing even
more (and not suffering a 14% attrition) if it hadn’t adopted a completely
moronic organizational model… so it still applies that you shouldn’t be a jerk
or try to implement organizations that any 14 years old kid could tell you are
plainly dysfunctional, real experience be damned (which by the way put all such
theories beyond the realm of falsifiability, as they hold no matter what
happens in “the real world”).
The other possible reaction is to go full
empirical, and declare that until every possible variable has been tallied and
correlated and its influence weighted in a big enough sample, no conclusion can
be reached. So, for example, if argue that simpler organizations are better
organizations, they would first make me clarify what I mean by “better” (can
they generate a greater return on invested capital? Do they exhibit higher
employee satisfaction scores in internal surveys? Do they create more
shareholder value in the short term?), then how I measure that simplicity
(although I proposed a fairly objective measure for that: total number of
different roles divided by number of members), and then they would want me to
measure both in a big enough number of organizations, spanning multiple
sectors, multiple countries, and if possible, multiple years, to see if the
relationship holds and there is a certain coefficient in a multiple linear
regression model that can be considered significant.
Unfortunately both approaches seem to me
wrongheaded. The “damn the evidence, it just sounds reasonable so it must be
so” is naïve and doesn’t take into account the unavoidable confirmation bias we
humans have, that make us find plausible even the most unlikely propositions,
if we arrive at them gradually and each seem to reinforce some belief of us.
The “don’t make me loose time with intuitions, gimme the hard data” never seems
to consider enough variables or, even worse, satisfies itself with sample sizes
that end up being too small, because its conclusions rarely survive the test of
time, as any change in market conditions tend to unsettle all its
classifications (a couple books I recommended in the third post of this series
provide a nice confirmation of the vanishing validity of these methodologies: In Search of Excellence and What Really Works both identified a
number of companies as exhibiting the most promising features for being
resilient, solid, durable and, well… excellent, and a decade after their
publication most have vanished or underperformed their competition). It is a
sobering reminder of how little we understand about what helps a company thrive
and to what extent it may depend on pure chance (chance being just another
measure of our lack of knowledge) to read The
Halo Effect by Phil Rosenzweig, where he debunks a good deal of claims by
the “empiricists”.
So if neither an appeal to common sense nor a
recourse to hard data gathering are entirely acceptable solutions to sustain
the validity of a theory’s claims, how should we differentiate crackpot
theories (like holocracy) from valid ones? Well, we just have to admit that we
can’t, or at least that there is no universally valid rule, as any theory can
be valid within a certain domain of application and then fail miserably within
another, or after some time even in the original one. We shouldn’t think of
organizational design (or leadership education, or even information system
implementation) as an engineering problem, where if we can measure a certain
number of environment conditions and know the universal laws that the process
we are designing conforms to we can find an optimal configuration for such
process (be it the optimal output of a vacuum pump or the optimal concentration
of certain isotope of uranium in a fuel rod). We should rather think of those
endeavors more like the creation of a work of art (or, if we prefer to be a bit
humbler, the building of some instrument by an expert craftsman from somewhat
faulty raw materials) where we apply some heuristic rules and the best of our
experience (that may not be fully algorithmical, or even “algorithmizable”) to
some given elements, with their own resistance, their own peculiarities (be it
the hardness of the wood, the irregularities of the stone or the shades of the
paint we are about to use) that prevent us from knowing in advance how we may
best approach it, and require a certain flexibility from our part to extract
the best they can provide. As I explained in this post: More on science and pseudo-science
there is not (and there can not be) an agreed upon rule to differentiate the
“true” statements from the “false” ones in the humanistic disciplines (and
“management” can aspire to be a discipline at most, if it someday gets some
organizing principles and a hierarchy of authorities to put some order in the
cacophony of conflicting, contradictory claims that today vie for acceptance
within its domain). That is why I maintain that “human sciences” is an oxymoron
(and an unnecessary one at that, derived from the sad and untrue opinion that
science –meaning experimental, empirically verifiable, science- is the only
valid method of obtaining “valuable” knowledge).
So back again to the question that launched our
original enquiry, does it matter that “Emphast” is more successful (has a much
bigger market capitalization and still enjoys a substantial lead in market
share within its industry) even if it is further from ADVISE than it was in its
time of struggles? Well, I still say it does matter, and I still use it as an
exemplary case for a reason. I firmly believe an ADVISE organization is better
in an absolute sense for its members (as any minimally conscious individual
would tell you she prefers to exercise her freedom, be treated fairly and
equitably, fill her time meaningfully by her own decision and collaborate with
other similarly minded people as spontaneously as possible). This kind of
organization, in the economic sphere, fosters happier employees, and as
everybody knows happier employees tend to be more productive, make less errors
and produce overall more value than unhappy ones (it could be argued if, “not
all other things being equal”, the potential extra cost of keeping those
employees happy was more than compensated by the additional benefits derived
from their enhanced productivity and commitment, but that is, as I have already
said, a question that admits of no universal answer, and which should then be
analyzed separately for each particular case).
How then, do I explain the continued success of
a company that was becoming more “RACKET’y” (and should thus suffer from less
enthusiastic employees)? Well, with organizations, as with political systems,
it is not so much how good or bad you are absolutely, but how good or bad you
are compared with your competition. “Emphast”
should have suffered from the degradation of its ability to give its work force
what they truly wanted (starting with a viable path to partnership, or however
the equivalent position was called in a publicly traded company), but for that
to happen its competitors should have been able to keep offering something
similar to THEIR workforces. But as it happens, the whole “IT consultancy”
market (which, as much as they loved to talk about their strategy practice, and
their human resources practice, and their start up incubator practice, and
their M&A practice, is what they were really all about ,the rest being the
icing on the cake, nice to boast about but economically insignificant) was
going through a tectonic shift, from a relatively low volume, high value added
orientation to just the opposite (what, using a term that few know has
distinctly Marxian origins, was a more and more “commoditized” market) where
competition happened mainly around price and ability to deliver at enormous
scale, with the high margins of yore quickly imploding and the blazing careers
of the pioneers a thing of the past. So “Emphast” could mistreat its employees
as much as it wanted, because they were not going to find anywhere in the
outside world the deals of old, so they would rather stay there and adjust
their expectations downwards.
And I definitely don’t need any complex study,
survey, multiple linear regression analysis or even back of the envelope
calculation to tell me that is what happened, that is why it happened, and that
it is nicely explained by my model, which is why I find it valuable. And why I
intend to keep on using it in the organizations I work for.
No comments:
Post a Comment